commissioner.org  


it's only rock 'n' roll (but it gives me utility)
Source Jim Devine
Date 05/05/14/00:02

moneybox
Rockonomics and Its Uses
Finally, economic proof of Elton John's genius!
By Daniel Gross

In recent years, economists have been drawn to the music industry like
lawyers to a car wreck. Napster, Grokster, digital sampling, and
Chinese piracy have thrown the industry into chaos. Economists have
realized it's the best place to study what happens when new
technologies disrupt established industries. They have also realized
it's really fun.

Among the crowd rushing the stage is Alan Krueger, the Princeton labor
economist who is an expert on the minimum wage and many other things.
In a paper written with Marie Connolly, which managed to cite both
singer Paul Simon and Nobel Prize-winning economist Gary Becker,
Krueger set out to answer some fundamental questions of what he and
Connolly call "rockonomics." (This is not to be confused with
Freakonomics, the book co-written by University of Chicago economists
Steven D. Levitt and Stephen J. Dubner. [has anyone read this book?])
Why are Cher concerts so expensive? How have falling record sales and
the rise of downloading affected big-name stars? And what's the deal
with scalping?

As a business, rock and pop concerts seem to be more Whitney Houston
(fading icon) than Mariah Carey (survivor on the comeback trail). The
number of concerts held annually fell 16 percent from 1996 to 2003,
and the number of tickets sold fell from about 30 million in 2000 to
just 22 million in 2003. Only 31 percent of teenagers attended a rock
concert in 2000, compared with 40 percent in 1976.

The reason: higher prices. Between 1981 and 1996, Krueger and Connolly
found, ticket prices generally kept pace with inflation. But since
1996, they've risen much faster. From 1996 to 2003-a period in which
inflation was a muted 2.3 percent per year-concert prices rose by 8.9
percent annually. Ticket prices for concerts have also risen more
rapidly than those for other forms of entertainment.

And what's causing the higher prices? Clear Channel, the giant radio
and concert-promotion business run by the right-wing Mays family of
Texas, has often been painted as a malign force in the modern music
industry-monopolizing venues and driving up ticket prices. But Krueger
doesn't buy it. The company's market share of concert revenue has
fallen since 2001, even as prices continued to rise. And concert
prices have risen sharply in Europe and Canada, where Clear Channel
has no presence. Besides, Clear Channel just announced it will spin
off its live entertainment unit, which implies the company isn't
reaping extraordinary profits from it. "Don't blame Clear Channel,"
said Krueger in an interview. "Blame the downloaders."

Pop stars are charging higher prices because they're realizing less
income from sales of CDs and other forms of recorded music. "Only four
of the top 35 income-earners made more money from recordings than from
live concerts," Krueger and Connolly note. And for the top 35, "income
from touring exceeded income from record sales by a ratio of 7.5 to 1
in 2002."

In some ways, the rockonomy resembles the increasingly winner-take-all
American economy. The rich are getting richer, and it's good to be the
king or queen of pop. In 1982, the top 1 percent of artists banked 26
percent of ticket revenues; in 2003, they garnered 56 percent.

Baby-boomers are the primary driving force behind a lot of these
trends. Nostalgia-seeking, age-resisting boomers have more disposable
income than youngsters, and so have more to spend on expensive tickets
at the box office. Paul McCartney and the Rolling Stones topped the
income-earning chart in 2002. The top 16 earners in 2002 also included
1970s-vintage draws like Crosby, Stills, Nash & Young, the Eagles,
Elton John, and Bruce Springsteen. On tour, Barry Manilow and Neil
Diamond easily out-earn Britney Spears and Kid Rock.

Ticket pricing is an area in which market forces don't function very
smoothly, the economists concluded. At a surprising number of
concerts, all tickets are sold at the same price. If they did what
baseball stadiums and even some Broadway producers do-charge more for
the best seats and less for the not-so-good seats-rock stars could
capture revenues that usually go to scalpers. And in some instances,
this could add up to real money.

Krueger and 12 students surveyed 858 people at a Bruce Springsteen
concert in Philadelphia in October 2002, where all tickets were priced
at $75. But they found that between 20 and 25 percent of the seats
were ultimately resold at an average price of $280. Ironically, the
better the seat, the less likely it was to be sold. In other words,
the fortunates who could have sold their $75 fifth-row seats for
$1,000 tended to hold on to them, while the non-hard-core Bruce fan
who had paid $75 for a nosebleed seat was all too happy to part with
his stub for $280.

Rockonomics has its limits. Numbers can only tell us so much about a
singer's appeal. And there are questions about the consumer behavior
surrounding popular music that not even all the Beautiful Minds
assembled at Princeton could begin to attack. Celine Dion, for
example, outearned Rod Stewart in the rockonomics survey. Krueger and
Connolly asked, "On what objective, cardinal metric is Celine Dion
only slightly more talented than Rod Stewart?" Hey, the economist who
can find some "objective, cardinal metric" that proves Celine Dion
possesses any talent at all should be nominated for a Nobel Prize.

Daniel Gross (www.danielgross.net) writes Slate's "Moneybox" column.
You can e-mail him at moneybox@slate.com.

[View the list]


InternetBoard v1.0
Copyright (c) 1998, Joongpil Cho