commissioner.org  


"For all we know, there may not be a safe way down"
Source Marv Gandall
Date 09/10/19/20:54

Countdown to the next crisis is already under way
By Wolfgang Munchau
Financial Times

WE DID NOT NEED to wait until the Dow Jones Industrial Average hit 10,000.
It has been clear for some time that global equity markets are bubbling
again. On the surface, this looks like 2003 and 2004 when the previous
housing, credit, commodity and equity bubbles started to inflate, helped by
low nominal interest rates and a lack of inflation. There is one big
difference, though. This bubble will burst sooner.

So how do we know this is a bubble? My two favourite metrics of stock market
valuation are Cape, which stands for the cyclically adjusted price/earnings
ratio, and Q. Cape was invented by Robert Shiller, professor of economics
and finance at Yale University. It measures the 10-year moving average of
the inflation-adjusted p/e ratio. Q is a metric of market capitalisation
divided by net worth. Andrew Smithers* has collected the data on Q, a
concept invented by the economist James Tobin.

Cape and Q measure different things. Yet they both tend to agree on relative
market mispricing most of the time. In mid-September both measures concluded
that the US stock market was overvalued by some 35 to 40 per cent. The
markets have since gone up a lot more than the moving average of earnings.
You can do the maths.

The single reason for this renewed bubble is the extremely low level of
nominal interest rates, which has induced people to move into all kinds of
risky assets. Even house prices are rising again. They never fell to the
levels consistent with long-term price-to-rent and price-to-income ratios,
which are reliable metrics of the property markets’ relative under- or
over-valuation.

But unlike five years ago, central banks now have the dual role of targeting
monetary and financial stability. As has been pointed out time and again,
those two objectives can easily come into conflict. In Europe, for example,
the European Central Bank would under normal circumstances already have
started to raise interest rates. The reason it sits tight is to prevent
damage to Europe’s chronically under-capitalised banking system, which still
depends on the ECB for life support. The same is true, more or less,
elsewhere.

Now, I agree there is no prospect of a significant rise in inflation over
the next 12 months, but the chances rise significantly after 2010.

Once perceptions of rising inflation return, central banks might be forced
to switch towards a much more aggressive monetary policy relatively
quickly – much quicker than during the previous cycle. A short inflationary
boom could be followed by another recession, another banking crisis, and
perhaps deflation. We should not see inflation and deflation as opposite
scenarios, but as sequential ones. We could be in for a period of extreme
price instability, in both directions, as central banks lose control.

This is exactly what the economist Hyman Minsky predicted in his financial
instability hypothesis. He postulated that a world with a large financial
sector and an excessive emphasis on the production of investment goods
creates instability both in terms of output and prices.

While, according to Minsky, these are the deep causes of instability, the
mechanism through which instability comes about is the way governments and
central banks respond to crises. The state has potent means to end a
recession, but the policies it uses give rise to the next phase of
instability. Minsky made that observation on the basis of data mostly from
the 1970s and early 1980s, but his theory describes very well what has been
happening to the global economy ever since, especially in the past decade.
The world has witnessed a proliferation of financial bubbles and extreme
economic instability that cannot be explained by any of the established
macroeconomic models. Minsky is about all we have.

His policy conclusions are disturbing, especially if contrasted with what is
actually happening. In their crisis response, world leaders have focused on
bonuses and other irrelevant side-issues. But they have failed to address
the financial sector’s overall size. So if Minsky is right, instability
should continue and get worse.

Our present situation can give rise to two scenarios – or some combination
of the two. The first is that central banks start exiting at some point in
2010, triggering another fall in the prices of risky assets. In the UK, for
example, any return to a normal monetary policy will almost inevitably imply
another fall in the housing market, which is currently propped up by
ultra-cheap mortgages.

Alternatively, central banks might prioritise financial stability over price
stability and keep the monetary floodgates open for as long as possible.
This, I believe, would cause the mother of all financial market crises – a
bond market crash – to be followed by depression and deflation.

In other words, there is danger no matter how the central banks react.
Successful monetary policy could be like walking along a perilous ridge, on
either side of which lies a precipice of instability.

For all we know, there may not be a safe way down.

[View the list]


InternetBoard v1.0
Copyright (c) 1998, Joongpil Cho